Verwandte Artikel zu The Development Dilemma: Security, Prosperity, and...

The Development Dilemma: Security, Prosperity, and a Return to History - Hardcover

 
9780691167350: The Development Dilemma: Security, Prosperity, and a Return to History

Inhaltsangabe

Reassessing the developing world through the lens of Europe's past Today's developing nations emerged from the rubble of the Second World War. Only a handful of these countries have subsequently attained a level of prosperity and security comparable to that of the advanced industrial world. The implication is clear: those who study the developing world in order to learn how development can be achieved lack the data to do so. In The Development Dilemma, Robert Bates responds to this challenge by turning to history, focusing on England and France. By the end of the eighteenth century, England stood poised to enter "the great transformation." France by contrast verged on state failure, and life and property were insecure. Probing the histories of these countries, Bates uncovers a powerful tension between prosperity and security: both may be necessary for development, he argues, but efforts to achieve the one threaten the achievement of the other. A fundamental tension pervades the political economy of development. Bates also argues that while the creation of a central hierarchy--a state--may be necessary to the achievement of development, it is not sufficient. What matters is how the power of the state is used. France and England teach us that in some settings the seizure and redistribution of wealth--not its safeguarding and fostering--is a winning political strategy. These countries also suggest the features that mark those settings--features that appear in nations throughout the developing world. Returning to the present, Bates applies these insights to the world today. Drawing on fieldwork in Zambia and Kenya, and data from around the globe, he demonstrates how the past can help us to understand the performance of nations in today's developing world.

Die Inhaltsangabe kann sich auf eine andere Ausgabe dieses Titels beziehen.

Über die Autorin bzw. den Autor

Robert H. Bates is the Eaton Professor of the Science of Government and professor of African and African American Studies at Harvard University. His books include Open-Economy Politics and Analytic Narratives (both Princeton).

Von der hinteren Coverseite

"In The Development Dilemma, Robert Bates turns to European history and Africa today to make a provocative argument: countries that throw different ethnic groups and regions together end up cutting deals that trade off growth to obtain stability. These kinds of historical comparisons are too rare and why this book is so important."--Chris Blattman, University of Chicago

"The Development Dilemma offers an elegant account of why some countries flourish when others do not. Familism, regionalism, colonialism, migration, institutions, and culture are important, but the resolute focus is on sources of political power. How key actors play the political game largely determines the consequent distribution of security, prosperity, and justice. Drawing on politics, economics, and world history, Robert Bates proves himself once again the doyen of development theory."--Margaret Levi, coauthor of In the Interest of Others

"This is a major contribution to debates on the political economy of development. Robert Bates examines the microfoundations of political decision making in early modern England and France to shed light on the terrain that shaped politics in modern Kenya and Zambia. He connects these case studies to an insightful, original argument on the political choices that foster or obstruct economic growth. A must-read for theorists and historians of economic development."--John Coatsworth, Columbia University

"Robert Bates's singular achievement is knitting together his case studies into one grand analytical narrative. His work is the imaginative culmination of the most important research program in contemporary political science."--Mark Lichbach, University of Maryland

"With forceful prose and vivid case studies, The Development Dilemma makes a significant contribution not just to the study of political and economic development but also to the social sciences more broadly."--Philip T. Hoffman, author of Why Did Europe Conquer the World?

Auszug. © Genehmigter Nachdruck. Alle Rechte vorbehalten.

The Development Dilemma

Security, Prosperity, and a Return to History

By Robert H. Bates

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS

Copyright © 2017 Princeton University Press
All rights reserved.
ISBN: 978-0-691-16735-0

Contents

List of Illustrations, ix,
Preface, xi,
1 Introduction, 1,
2 The Fundamental Tension, 14,
3 Taming the Hierarchy, 25,
4 Forging the Political Terrain, 49,
5 The Developing World: Two Examples, 62,
6 The Use of Power, 87,
7 Conclusion, 115,
Addendum to Chapter 2, 129,
Addendum to Chapter 6, 135,
Addendum to Chapter 7, 141,
Notes, 151,
Bibliography, 169,
Index, 181,


CHAPTER 1

Introduction


After pondering the disparity in income between rich nations and poor, Robert Lucas famously stated: "Once one starts to think about [the problem], it is difficult to think about anything else." Humanitarians, policymakers, and scholars have joined Lucas in addressing the determinants of development; and in this volume, I, a political scientist, join them.

Among those who seek to account for the disparities in income that mark the modern world, economists, such as Lucas, stand supreme. Not only do they rank among the most skilled and insightful of those who study development, but also they dominate the agencies that fund programs and design policies for those who strive to achieve it. But clearly, the problems bedeviling efforts to promote prosperity in the developing world are not purely economic in nature. Some arise from cultural values and religious beliefs; others from biological and environmental forces; and still others from politics. I shall focus on the impact of politics. I shall focus in particular on politicians, their use of power, and their impact on development.

Development, I contend, contains two elements: one economic, the level of prosperity; and the second political, the degree of security. From this perspective, societies can be considered more developed the greater their prosperity and the more secure the lives and property of those who inhabit them. Some might object to the use of income, and especially average income, as a measure of development. But clearly the attainment of other valued outcomes is costly and prosperous societies are better positioned to secure them than are those that are poor. As for security, I take counsel from Hobbes, who noted that where "the life of man is nasty, poor, brutish and short," there is "no place for industries, because the future thereof is uncertain ... no knowledge of the face of the earth; ... no arts; no letters; and what is worst of all, continuous fear, and danger of violent death." Both prosperity and security are valuable, then, not only in their own right but also because they make possible the attainment of other values.

Throughout this book, I probe the political foundations of development.


Method and Substance

Most who study development proceed "cross-sectionally"; that is, they compare poor nations to rich ones and note how differences in, say, education, gender equality, investment, or corruption relate to differences in standards of living. But development is a dynamic phenomenon and involves change over time. It is best studied, then, by seeing how nations evolve. Not only that: only a handful of nations in today's developing world have achieved a standard of living comparable to that of nations in the developed world; and in many, life and property remain imperiled. The number of "successes" is small; and because most of these reside in the Pacific Rim, so too is the amount of variation in the sample they provide. Today's world thus provides us little information. The implications are profound: today's world supplies little insight into how nations develop.

In response to this difficulty, I turn to history. Rather than proceeding cross-sectionally, and comparing poor countries with rich in the contemporary world, I proceed "longitudinally" and explore, for a given set of countries, how they changed over time. For reasons that I will soon discuss, I focus on England and France in the medieval and early modern periods. At the end of the latter, England stood poised to undergo the "great transformation" whereas France stood on the verge of political collapse. Attempts to isolate the factors that rendered the one more successful than the other can therefore offer insight into the factors that promote or impede the attainment of prosperity and security.

To use historical materials in this fashion, we have to assure ourselves that at least two conditions are met. The first is that the historical cases be sufficiently similar that inferences can be drawn from their divergent responses to similar stimuli. The second is to find a way of moving from "what is known" — the historical cases — to what cannot yet be known — the determinants of development in the contemporary world. We now turn to these issues.


TURNING TO HISTORY

The principal justification for drawing inferences from a comparison between England and France is that politically, economically, linguistically, and culturally, in the medieval and early modern periods, England and France shared important characteristics in common.

The England we first encounter was ruled by the Normans. And the Normans, like the Angevins that followed, presided not only over England but also over their "homelands" in what now is France (see figure 1.1). England's governing classes held properties on both sides of the channel, which they crossed and recrossed to manage and defend. The ruling lineages intermarried and incessantly fought each other. On both sides of the channel, the elite spoke the same language and until the sixteenth century belonged to the same church. That the two cases shared such basic characteristics in common, I argue, enables us to relate their differences to variations in the developmental outcomes that emerge over time: the one, becoming richer and more powerful; the other, a failed state.


USES OF THE PAST

Turning to a second challenge, we ask: How are we to employ our knowledge of history to gain insight into the contemporary world?

We do so by noting that in the medieval and early modern periods, Western societies were agrarian and that the underdeveloped nations remain largely so today. The attributes that commonly mark agrarian societies offer a framework that enables us to compare the two sets of cases; they enable us to treat them as members of a similar class. While accommodating, the framework (see box 1.1) is also powerful: it highlights regularities that enable us to draw on what is known about one set of cases to shed light on another. By so doing, it enables us to better comprehend the impact of power upon the process of development.


AGRARIAN ECONOMIES

As can be seen in box 1.1, two powerful regularities characterize agrarian economies, one governing production and the other consumption. The first is the law of diminishing returns. Derived by David Ricardo, a student of England's agrarian economy, the law states that as population grows, because the quantity of land remains fixed, per capita output declines. The first settlers would work the most productive land; as the population grows and people spread out, they then move to lands of lower quality. Should they instead remain on the most fertile plot, as their numbers increase, they would have to farm more intensively or make use of less productive labor, such as the aged. The increase in population therefore results in less output per unit of labor. By the law of diminishing returns, as this regularity is known, in agrarian societies, over time, average incomes decline and people become poor.

The second law characterizes consumption. Named after Ernst Engel — a statistician who studied household economics in Germany — the law holds that the lower a person's income, the greater the percentage of her budget that she will spend on food. Food is a necessity, after all; to survive, a person must eat. Should she become poor, she will therefore curtail her expenditures on other commodities and devote her income to the purchase of food.

The two laws pertain to individuals who produce and consume. While thus "micro" in scope, they generate "macrolevel" implications. By Engel's Law, poor societies are agrarian; and by the law of diminishing returns, agrarian societies become poor. These regularities permeate both premodern Europe and the less developed portions of the contemporary world and mark them both as underdeveloped.

There are few laws in the social sciences. That two of the few we possess pertain to agrarian societies is fortuitous and encourages us to believe that premodern Europe and the contemporary developing world may abide by common logics. They encourage us to believe as well that insights extracted from the one can deepen our understanding of the other, even if the two inhabit different places and times.

From these laws, other regularities follow, and these too offer points of entry for those who wish to use history for the study of development. To fend off declines in income in agrarian societies, people specialize in production and engage in trade. One result is regional differentiation, with wine, say, being produced in one location; timber and charcoal in another; and meat, hides, and dairy products in yet a third. Another is commerce. As trade and markets span these diverse settings, they enable people to exchange the surpluses they produce locally for goods that may be produced more cheaply in other locations. In response to diminishing returns, people also migrate. They venture forth in search of new places to settle. As we shall see, regional differentiation and migration — both responses to decreasing returns — shaped the politics of development in medieval and early modern Europe and shapes it in the developing world today as well.

As suggested by Engel's Law, a third, "macrolevel" implication emerges: as incomes rise, the relative size of the rural sector declines. With development, agriculture gives way to industry and manufacturing, with factories replacing farms, towns displacing villages, and labor shifting from farming to commerce and industry. Development thus involves "structural change," in the words of some, or a "great transformation," in the phrasing of others. To study the political foundations of development is to study the politics of these changes.

Two economic "laws" thus provide a structure that enables us to place medieval and early modern Europe within the same framework as the contemporary developing world and to focus on a common set of themes: regional specialization, migration, and the impact of structural change.

A last major regularity characterizes agrarian societies. It is the importance of kinship. In both agrarian and industrial societies, families govern consumption; they allocate the household budget. But in agrarian societies, they govern production as well; they assign tasks in home and field to the members of the household. Kinship and the family also govern the polity. Offices and titles are transmitted by the rules of descent. Polities are often governed by dynasties and localities by groups of kin. And it is the family that provides security: by brandishing arms, its members deter those who might seek to encroach upon them. When we study the economics and the politics of agrarian societies, be they in the historical West or the contemporary developing world, we shall focus on the role of the family.

Because of their agrarian nature, medieval and early modern Europe and the developing world share key features in common. This common set of features constitutes what I call a "political terrain": a setting within which politicians compete for power. As we shall see, the composition of that terrain determines what kinds of actions are "winning" and therefore how those with power are likely to behave. Examining the historical cases enables us to infer the features that appear to have led to the productive use of power in one case and to its destructive use in another, thus suggesting lessons that should inform our understanding of development in the contemporary world.


THE ROLE OF EMPIRE

Many will bridle at this approach. Conceding the presence of commonalities, they would also stress the importance of differences between medieval and early modern Europe and the developing world today. The challenge of development today differs from that in the past, they would contend, for nations today are attempting to develop in a world dominated by those who are far richer and more powerful than themselves.

By way of rejoinder, I advance two counterarguments. First, as does the developing world today, in the medieval and early modern periods, Europe confronted others whose wealth and power were greater than their own. It felt threatened by the Caliphates, the Turks, and invaders from the steppes. It had lost holy shrines and religious capitals to those who fought in the name of a god other than their own. It was aware of the riches of "Cathay" and the Middle East and the power of those who invaded from the east and south. Europe thus emerged in a world dominated by societies wealthier and more powerful than itself. Second, I shall in fact stress the impact upon the developing world of its subjugation to Europe. And when doing so, I shall note how Europe's hegemony rendered the developing world similar to its "slow developing" predecessor — to France, that is, rather than to England.

Placing both the developing world and historical cases within a common frame thus enables us to levy insights from historical Europe, where development has been achieved, to the contemporary world, where for many development remains an aspiration.

We now move from matters of method to matters of substance.


Core Tension

Throughout this work, we note a pervasive tension — one that takes two forms. The first arises in societies in which power lies in private hands.

When security is provided by families, then development, we find, cannot be achieved. To achieve development, a society must be both prosperous and secure. But when private families control both production and coercion, then they must choose: to be secure, it is best that they possess little worth stealing. And should they wish to prosper, they had better prepare to fight, for others will seek to prey upon them. In such societies, people can be prosperous or be secure. They find it difficult to be both.

As we shall see, this insight informs our understanding of institutional change. In medieval Europe, societies prospered, cities formed, farming became more profitable, and incomes rose. But with the growth of prosperity came the spread of violence. The result was a demand for a new political order: the movement of the control of coercion from private hands to a central agency, capable of providing the peaceful settlements of disputes.

Once coercion is reorganized in this fashion, however, the tension between prosperity and political order rises in another form. For, as noted by Weingast, "a government strong enough to protect property rights is also strong enough to confiscate the wealth of its citizens." For those who are interested in the political foundations of development, as am I, the central issue is thus how power is used and, in particular, whether it is employed to provide security and to underpin prosperity or to imperil and despoil. The comparison between England and France offers us insight into the factors that lead to different political choices and thus to different developmental outcomes. At the end of the early modern period, England was poised to enter an industrial revolution while France was poised for state failure.

The factors that appear to account for the difference in the manner in which power was employed in England and France cast light as well on the trajectories traced by Zambia and Kenya: the two cases we draw from the developing world. As is often the situation in the developing world, in these two countries, periods of rapid economic growth were followed by abrupt reversals. Given the attributes that Kenya and Zambia share with other agrarian polities and other portions of the postcolonial world, the factors that shaped the behavior of those who governed these two countries surely operate elsewhere, and in the last portion of the book I seek to isolate them.


Situating the Argument

The arguments I mount both echo and dissent from the works of others. Of greatest relevance is Huntington, who, as do I, cautions that economic growth can be politically disruptive and lead to conflict between regions, between communities, and between town and country. Huntington too stresses the importance of political order and the need for institutions to achieve it. While my work therefore re-echoes his, I take a more historical turn. I strive, moreover, to explore the "microfoundations" of my arguments and how individual actions generate the collective outcomes we observe: poverty and disorder, on the one hand, and prosperity and security on the other. I am also far less sanguine than is he about the impact of hierarchical institutions and stress that while they may be necessary for achieving development, they clearly are not sufficient.

Acemoglu and Robinson, like Huntington, focus on the manner in which political institutions promote — or impede — economic development. In advancing their arguments, they — as do I — turn to history. In contrast to Acemoglu and Robinson, however, I am less inclined to stress the impact of institutions and more inclined to stress the impact of other factors — economic and social — that shape political incentives and the use of power in agrarian societies. And I am also more inclined to draw upon agricultural economics and ethnography when doing so.


(Continues...)
Excerpted from The Development Dilemma by Robert H. Bates. Copyright © 2017 Princeton University Press. Excerpted by permission of PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

„Über diesen Titel“ kann sich auf eine andere Ausgabe dieses Titels beziehen.

Gebraucht kaufen

Zustand: Befriedigend
Item in good condition. Textbooks...
Diesen Artikel anzeigen

Gratis für den Versand innerhalb von/der USA

Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

EUR 3,41 für den Versand innerhalb von/der USA

Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Weitere beliebte Ausgaben desselben Titels

9780691210193: The Development Dilemma: Security, Prosperity, and a Return to History

Vorgestellte Ausgabe

ISBN 10:  0691210195 ISBN 13:  9780691210193
Verlag: Princeton University Press, 2020
Softcover

Suchergebnisse für The Development Dilemma: Security, Prosperity, and...

Beispielbild für diese ISBN

Bates, Robert H.
ISBN 10: 0691167354 ISBN 13: 9780691167350
Gebraucht Hardcover

Anbieter: SecondSale, Montgomery, IL, USA

Verkäuferbewertung 5 von 5 Sternen 5 Sterne, Erfahren Sie mehr über Verkäufer-Bewertungen

Zustand: Good. Item in good condition. Textbooks may not include supplemental items i.e. CDs, access codes etc. Bestandsnummer des Verkäufers 00060695642

Verkäufer kontaktieren

Gebraucht kaufen

EUR 5,25
Währung umrechnen
Versand: Gratis
Innerhalb der USA
Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Anzahl: 1 verfügbar

In den Warenkorb

Beispielbild für diese ISBN

Bates, Robert H.
ISBN 10: 0691167354 ISBN 13: 9780691167350
Gebraucht Hardcover

Anbieter: Wonder Book, Frederick, MD, USA

Verkäuferbewertung 5 von 5 Sternen 5 Sterne, Erfahren Sie mehr über Verkäufer-Bewertungen

Zustand: Very Good. Very Good condition. Good dust jacket. A copy that may have a few cosmetic defects. May also contain light spine creasing or a few markings such as an owner's name, short gifter's inscription or light stamp. Bestandsnummer des Verkäufers T13O-00505

Verkäufer kontaktieren

Gebraucht kaufen

EUR 5,27
Währung umrechnen
Versand: Gratis
Innerhalb der USA
Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Anzahl: 1 verfügbar

In den Warenkorb

Beispielbild für diese ISBN

Bates, Robert H.
ISBN 10: 0691167354 ISBN 13: 9780691167350
Gebraucht Hardcover

Anbieter: Better World Books, Mishawaka, IN, USA

Verkäuferbewertung 5 von 5 Sternen 5 Sterne, Erfahren Sie mehr über Verkäufer-Bewertungen

Zustand: Very Good. Used book that is in excellent condition. May show signs of wear or have minor defects. Bestandsnummer des Verkäufers 14759923-6

Verkäufer kontaktieren

Gebraucht kaufen

EUR 6,06
Währung umrechnen
Versand: Gratis
Innerhalb der USA
Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Anzahl: 1 verfügbar

In den Warenkorb

Beispielbild für diese ISBN

Bates, Robert H.
ISBN 10: 0691167354 ISBN 13: 9780691167350
Gebraucht Hardcover

Anbieter: Better World Books, Mishawaka, IN, USA

Verkäuferbewertung 5 von 5 Sternen 5 Sterne, Erfahren Sie mehr über Verkäufer-Bewertungen

Zustand: Very Good. Former library book; may include library markings. Used book that is in excellent condition. May show signs of wear or have minor defects. Bestandsnummer des Verkäufers 16466852-6

Verkäufer kontaktieren

Gebraucht kaufen

EUR 6,06
Währung umrechnen
Versand: Gratis
Innerhalb der USA
Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Anzahl: 1 verfügbar

In den Warenkorb

Beispielbild für diese ISBN

Bates, Robert H.
ISBN 10: 0691167354 ISBN 13: 9780691167350
Gebraucht Hardcover

Anbieter: Books-FYI, Inc., Cadiz, KY, USA

Verkäuferbewertung 5 von 5 Sternen 5 Sterne, Erfahren Sie mehr über Verkäufer-Bewertungen

hardcover. Zustand: Good. Bestandsnummer des Verkäufers 23MA36017CEL_ns

Verkäufer kontaktieren

Gebraucht kaufen

EUR 3,25
Währung umrechnen
Versand: EUR 2,98
Innerhalb der USA
Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Anzahl: 1 verfügbar

In den Warenkorb

Beispielbild für diese ISBN

Bates, Robert H.
ISBN 10: 0691167354 ISBN 13: 9780691167350
Gebraucht Hardcover

Anbieter: Half Price Books Inc., Dallas, TX, USA

Verkäuferbewertung 5 von 5 Sternen 5 Sterne, Erfahren Sie mehr über Verkäufer-Bewertungen

hardcover. Zustand: Very Good. Connecting readers with great books since 1972! Used books may not include companion materials, and may have some shelf wear or limited writing. We ship orders daily and Customer Service is our top priority! Bestandsnummer des Verkäufers S_421649894

Verkäufer kontaktieren

Gebraucht kaufen

EUR 3,52
Währung umrechnen
Versand: EUR 2,98
Innerhalb der USA
Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Anzahl: 1 verfügbar

In den Warenkorb

Beispielbild für diese ISBN

Bates, Robert H.
ISBN 10: 0691167354 ISBN 13: 9780691167350
Gebraucht Hardcover

Anbieter: Academybookshop, Long Island City, NY, USA

Verkäuferbewertung 4 von 5 Sternen 4 Sterne, Erfahren Sie mehr über Verkäufer-Bewertungen

Hardcover. Zustand: As New. In fine, clean condition, but WITHOUT THE DUST-COVER, clean pages. Bestandsnummer des Verkäufers F-gj24-05999

Verkäufer kontaktieren

Gebraucht kaufen

EUR 4,05
Währung umrechnen
Versand: EUR 3,41
Innerhalb der USA
Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Anzahl: 1 verfügbar

In den Warenkorb

Beispielbild für diese ISBN

Bates, Robert H.
ISBN 10: 0691167354 ISBN 13: 9780691167350
Gebraucht Hardcover

Anbieter: Academybookshop, Long Island City, NY, USA

Verkäuferbewertung 4 von 5 Sternen 4 Sterne, Erfahren Sie mehr über Verkäufer-Bewertungen

Hardcover. Zustand: Very Good. This is a new book that has some damage, which is usually a tear, a scratch, dents or stain on the edge, pages are clean, no missing pages. Bestandsnummer des Verkäufers A-gj24-36936

Verkäufer kontaktieren

Gebraucht kaufen

EUR 4,05
Währung umrechnen
Versand: EUR 3,41
Innerhalb der USA
Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Anzahl: 1 verfügbar

In den Warenkorb

Beispielbild für diese ISBN

Bates, Robert H.
ISBN 10: 0691167354 ISBN 13: 9780691167350
Gebraucht Hardcover

Anbieter: Academybookshop, Long Island City, NY, USA

Verkäuferbewertung 4 von 5 Sternen 4 Sterne, Erfahren Sie mehr über Verkäufer-Bewertungen

Hardcover. Zustand: As New. In fine, clean condition, but WITHOUT THE DUST-COVER, clean pages. Bestandsnummer des Verkäufers N-gj24-09521

Verkäufer kontaktieren

Gebraucht kaufen

EUR 4,05
Währung umrechnen
Versand: EUR 3,41
Innerhalb der USA
Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Anzahl: 1 verfügbar

In den Warenkorb

Beispielbild für diese ISBN

Bates, Robert H.
ISBN 10: 0691167354 ISBN 13: 9780691167350
Neu Hardcover

Anbieter: Academybookshop, Long Island City, NY, USA

Verkäuferbewertung 4 von 5 Sternen 4 Sterne, Erfahren Sie mehr über Verkäufer-Bewertungen

Hardcover. Zustand: New. Bestandsnummer des Verkäufers 25-5-Dilemma

Verkäufer kontaktieren

Neu kaufen

EUR 7,22
Währung umrechnen
Versand: EUR 3,41
Innerhalb der USA
Versandziele, Kosten & Dauer

Anzahl: 6 verfügbar

In den Warenkorb

Es gibt 24 weitere Exemplare dieses Buches

Alle Suchergebnisse ansehen